From: | "Peter B Meyer" <pbmeyer@louisville.edu> |
Date: | 22 Jul 2007 06:13:12 -0000 |
Reply: | cpeo-brownfields |
Subject: | Re: [CPEO-BIF] Brownfield Subsidies |
I’m responding to Larry Schnapf’s last message, with an eye to the rest of you … I’m repeating his notes here, inserting my comments in [* starred brackets *] so that you all can see where he and I agree and where we part company. I conclude with a recommendation for revising the NY State program that yields all the argument to Larry’s claims, even where I have contested them. ******** thanks all for your comments. Not being an economist, I was just wondering if there was some formula that can be applied to figure out the taxes that are likely to be thrown off by a project without going into a detailed study if the project results in a "net" benefit to the state as a whole. For example, if we know a developer will be building a $200 million project, arent there multipliers are other metrics that can be used to figure out the jobs created [* no, since even for a single use – say retail – the type of store determines how many employees there are per square foot of area … and the same applies to sales taxes from the retain establishment. Obviously, housing developments produce fewer future jobs than new business facilities. *] , income taxes generated [* would first depend on construction payroll which is not directly determinable, especially with regard to mitigation activities, and post-construction would have the same problem relative to facility use as above *] , sales taxes from raw materials used and sale of condos, property taxes from the development, etc. [* all these depend on the current tax rates, which may change with new development – and very commonly are waived or reduced as a development incentive, such as in most states’ ”enterprise zones” *] This might simplistic but at least it presents an estimate of some of the benefits thrown off by a project that can offset the tax credit liability generated by the project. [* the issue in the approach you are pursuing, Larry, is not being “simplistic,” but failing to calculate any of the indirect and not immediately monetizable effects of a project. In failing to, for example, consider the benefit of reduced health care costs to a community resulting from a site mitigation, you may UNDER-subsidize. My argument is that the narrow direct monetary impact calculation fails to allocate efficiently, not that subsidies are too high. *] I do not think that the creation of an environmental fund for use by the state to acquire, remediate and then sell property to developers makes any sense. First, the state cannot cleanup as many sites as developers can and certainly not in the time frame required by the market. The Wollman Rink in Central Park was a perfect example. The City tried for years to get it reconstructed. Trump stepped in, hired contractors that were incentivized to complete the work within certain time periods (and without having to do the bidding procedures) and had the rink built in a year. When the state gets involved, the low bids frequently up with sloppy and sometimes tragic results like what happened with the Boston Harbor tunnel. [* I agree that no state does not now have an agency or mechanism to do what I suggested. But I disagree that the state could not “cleanup as many sites as developers can.” If a special agency (not just “a fund”) were created, it could be given the powers you ascribe to Trump relative to New York (the City, for our non-New York City readers). All the requirements for bid procedures by public agencies are a matter of state law, not constitutional requirement, and could be modified if the will were there. You tell the story of the Boston Harbor Tunnel. I can tell stories about arena roofs collapsing, terraces falling in hotels and other shoddy private developments. Anecdotes do not guide us well.*} Having done a numerous brownfield sites across the country either representing developers or lenders, my experience is that tax credits are the most efficient and fastest way to redevelop contaminated properties. Loans and grants may be ok for local governments to perform assessments but tax credits work great for developers since they dont have to deal with bureaucratic delays and inadequate staffing, and the developers along with their contractors are incentivized to get the project done quickly so they can then file for their financial benefits. [* Your argument in favor of tax credits is 100% accurate for large scale, well-financed developers with ready access to credit. The majority of the brownfields in the US are under 1 acre in size. The developers you work with are not likely to be interested in such small properties, and the developers who are may need financial assistance long before they earned the returns against which they would use their tax credits. We thus need additional subsidy/financial incentive tools for the smaller scale projects. One size does NOT fit all in brownfields, as the discussion has already shown with respect to brownfields in different real estate markets. *] Also, there was a comment about subsidies and trivial level contamination. Regulators and environmental professionals may view some amounts of contamination as trivial but contamination still sends shudders through the development and lending community because of the cost and timing uncertainty. [* The uncertainty over cost and timing, which can exist even when a site appears to have minimal contamination was precisely the reason I suggested that the state take on the cleanup role. Then the taxpayers would not have to compensate developers for such risks and would, in effect, insure themselves from over-subsidizing by spreading the risks of problems over far more sites than any one developer would take on. *] Despite liability reforms, many developers are still nervous about touching even slightly contaminated properties. I've been involved in situations where I have spent more than a year explaining the benefits of a state brownfield program before a client was willing to pull the trigger on a project. These projects are viewed as risky and high risk money demands high rewards. [* Precisely my point, Larry – that’s why a state operation designed to accept and control the risk would cost taxpayers less than subsidizing private risk taking. *] With construction costs increasing 5-10% a month, any delays can have devastating effects on the rate of return and make projects uneconomical. [* 5-10% a MONTH? Come on, Larry, we’ve had occasional spikes in construction costs but costs are not rising at 50+% a year. Your concern about delay is valid even if construction costs rise 5-10% a year, so why exaggerate? *] And of course, it seems each year we become concerned about more types of chemicals at ever lower levels of exposure. Thus, I would never underestimate the impact of "trivial" amounts of contamination at a site or the incentives needed to convince developers to take a risk on a contaminated property instead of a nice undeveloped parcel or land with a fairly benign use. [* Again, I agree on the problem, and I have my own horror stories about problems encountered in non-profit organization redevelopment efforts than ran afoul of changing standards. However, I do not have any evidence in hand to convince me that guaranteed subsidies that may amount to many multiples of the predicted – or, worse yet, actually experienced – cleanup costs are really needed to subsidize brownfield redevelopment in strong real estate markets. *] ******** A PROPOSAL Granting all of Larry’s points, including his assumption that no state could possibly be as efficient in handling risk as private developers, we can derive a set of principles for a far more cost-efficient and effective subsidy system using tax credits than now exists in New York: (1) Guarantee a maximum tax credit that is in proportion to total project costs, since some of those costs (purchase price paid, for example) may have to be carried for unexpect edly long periods of time if contamination results in unexpected delays. (2) Tie the level of the guarantee to the strength of the local property market, to allow for the difference in attractiveness of development investments in the New York City area as compared to upstate New York (and the equivalent differences exist in most other states); the guarantee should be higher in weaker markets. (3) Make the actual tax credit that will be available a matter of calculation after state approval of the completed site mitigation. The credit would be based on factor such as (a) expected site mitigation costs, (b) the ratio of the experienced site preparation costs to total project costs, (c) the extent to which actual site mitigation costs exceeded expected costs (including in the calculation costs associated with delays, loss of any premiums available from intended users for prompt delivery or penalties for delayed delivery of premises), (d) an additional allowance for market conditions documented per state specification in the initial application for a tax credit, thus determined prior to project initiation, where such the allowance would be a proportion of total project costs, (e) a further allowance adjusting for the number of years the developer would have to file taxes before collecting the full credit due (since the delay may be due to site mitigation problems). Thus the minimum credit would be known to the developer from the beginning, and the guarantees of additional credits to offset unexpected costs would also be known and thus would compensate for the exceptional uncertainty of a brownfield project. In the tax credit calculation under item (3) above, elements (a), (b), and (c) would be designed to compensate for the risks and uncertainties associated with brownfield site preparation, element (d) is the economic development, not brownfield, subsidy, and element (e) is basically an allowance for the time value of money, that is, interest. There is one piece of information the developer would have to provide under this logic that is not now required to apply for the NY state subsidy: documentation of actual site mitigation costs. Since the recipients of the tax credits are requesting that they be paid monies out of state coffers, it is not unreasonable to request that such information be provided. Participation in the brownfield tax credit program would always be voluntary, so there is no issue of a forced invasion of business privacy in such a state request. My one qualm in this scheme involves auditing and approving the claims about mitigation costs – and I would recommend that those claims, with associated documentation, be reviewed by both state employees and a private auditing firm, selected competitively every 2-3 years, to assure objectivity and conformance to private sector accounting standards. The actual guarantees and subsidy levels that are appropriate will always be a matter of political debate, and I won’t enter into that discussion here. This proposal is a response to a particular NY State scheme that is now under review, and it may not be appropriate for other jurisdictions. The issue of how to support small scale brownfields (the under 1 acre or even under 0.5 acre sites) remains unresolved under this scheme. Peter Peter B. Meyer Professor Emeritus of Urban Policy and Economics Director, Center for Environmental Policy & Management University of Louisville WEB: <http://cepm.louisville.edu> - - - - - Director of Applied Research Center for Public Leadership and Public Affairs Northern Kentucky University - - - - - - 3205 Huntersridge Lane Taylor Mill, KY 41015 502-45-3240 (cell) _______________________________________________ Brownfields mailing list Brownfields@list.cpeo.org http://www.cpeo.org/mailman/listinfo/brownfields | |
References
| |
Prev by Date: [CPEO-BIF] Brownfield Subsidies Next by Date: [Fwd: RE: [CPEO-BIF] Brownfield Subsidies] | |
Prev by Thread: [CPEO-BIF] Brownfield Subsidies Next by Thread: [Fwd: RE: [CPEO-BIF] Brownfield Subsidies] |